You can set your main menu in Appearance → Menus

Author: PRIME Institute

Pakistan Economic Freedom Audit: Sound Money as a Case Study

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

Pakistan Economic Freedom Audit: Sound Money as a Case Study

This study presents an economic freedom audit of Pakistan, focusing on sound money as a case study. The success of free market capitalism is contingent upon protecting individual property rights. The Fraser Institute's Annual Report on Economic Freedom of the World assesses countries based on their economic freedom index, which comprises five areas, including sound money. This economic freedom audit report aims to evaluate Pakistan's monetary stability and analyze the macroeconomic policies that have shaped its current state. Furthermore, the report critically evaluates the methodology of the sound money sub-index to determine its efficacy in measuring economic freedom.

Pakistan's rating for monetary stability has been consistently low for the past two decades and has further declined in 2023. Historically, Pakistan has had a sound money rating of less than seven due to restrictions on residents having foreign currency accounts and monetary expansion exceeding real GDP growth. Fluctuations in the sound money rating were driven by recent inflation, its volatility, and monetary growth in the near past, as the score on foreign currency accounts remained stable. Pakistan's historical data reveals that sound money rating has typically risen during economic recessions caused by demand contraction but has fallen during periods of cost-push inflation. Recent assessments reveal that Pakistan's sound money rating for 2023 is 4.60, which is the lowest in history, primarily due to exceptionally high inflation during the year.

Throughout history, the fragility of money has been a persistent concern in Pakistan. The value of money has consistently depreciated over time, with a decline in its purchasing power for goods and services included in the CPI basket by one-tenth from 1974 to 2001 and one-sixty-eighths from 1974 to 2023. The Pakistani rupee (PKR) has also experienced a similar decline in value against foreign currencies. For instance, the value of one US dollar in Pakistani rupees increased from less than 10 in 1974 to 248 in 2023, resulting in a 25-fold cumulative loss.

Monetary fragility can be attributed to excessive monetary growth. The growth rate of broad money (M2) has consistently exceeded that of real GDP by a significant margin and has even surpassed nominal GDP growth. Real GDP has increased ten-fold over the past five decades, while nominal GDP has increased 644-fold. However, monetary growth during this period exceeded 1000 times, indicating inefficiencies in both monetary and fiscal policies that have contributed to this expansion and, ultimately, the devaluation of money. Since its inception, the Pakistani government has heavily relied on borrowing from the State Bank of Pakistan (SBP) to finance its budget, leading to an unsustainable monetary expansion. Although the amended SBP Act has limited the government's ability to issue its debt to the SBP, monetary expansion has continued. The SBP has provided the necessary liquidity to banks, which have, in turn, lent it to the government


Over the last five decades, the monetary value has been fragile and unstable, resulting from the misguided and ineffective implementation of monetary, fiscal, and exchange rate policies. Particularly, the short-term real interest rate has remained marginally negative and has shown poor responsiveness to rising inflation, exacerbating the problem. The State Bank of Pakistan has recently adopted a reactionary stance in response to inflation and currency depreciation. However, this approach proved to be ineffective as well. The interest rate, which serves as the SBP's monetary policy instrument, has yielded little success in controlling inflation and exchange rates. Furthermore, interest rate changes hurt economic activity, particularly in large-scale manufacturing. On the other hand, fiscal slippages emanating from increased spending without matching revenue have led to domestic debt accumulation. At the same time, the overvaluation of the exchange rate has caused a trade deficit, contributing to external debt accumulation. Both of these debts are responsible for the monetary fragility that Pakistan is currently facing.

The methodology used to rate sound money requires revision, particularly for developing countries. The rating scheme awards countries with the highest score for inflation and money growth components if they adhere to a zero inflation or deflationary policy. However, these policies are not preferred by any central bank globally; rather, they aim to maintain positive inflation. Additionally, inflation persistence may exhibit positive or negative trends over brief periods, making the standard deviation of five years’ inflation an inadequate indicator of the solidity of money.

This is because the standard deviation is a measure of variation that applies equally to both rising and declining inflation. Finally, there are limited options available for scores related to restrictions on foreign currency accounts within the country and overseas. For example, the State Bank of Pakistan permits foreign cu rrency bank accounts in Pakistan but restricts the flow of some types of funds into these accounts. Moreover, certain restrictions may sometimes hurt economic freedom, but their imposition can lead to more stable and sound money.While different countries may have varying degrees of restrictions, the current rating scheme fails to assign scores based on the severity of such restrictions.
A comprehensive reform agenda is needed to improve the solidity of money in Pakistan. The rationalization of government size, effective coordination between fiscal and monetary policies, efficient debt management, and establishment of an enabling environment for continuous economic growth, which provides equal opportunities to all, are pivotal requisites. It is crucial to re-evaluate the existing monetary-fiscal policy mix and ascertain the appropriate operating instrument for the State Bank of Pakistan to restrict monetary expansion and exercise its autonomy. Setting the policy rate to contain inflation while expanding the money supply as a response to government borrowing from scheduled banks is unproductive. A suitable monetary-fiscal coordination mechanism can be designed to overcome the high inflation and excessive debt predicament. Fiscal policy must adhere to the Fiscal Responsibility and Debt Limitation Act, and there is a need to put in place an accountability mechanism for the government's non-compliance, which can help limit the budget deficit and financing obligations. The government's economic intrusion must be reduced through reforms while simultaneously rendering tax policy more efficient. An Act of Parliament can restrict the deliberate overvaluation of the exchange rate, for which a suitable indicator needs to be developed

HISTORIC SEMINAR ON SECTION 7E OF THE INCOME TAX ORDINANCE, 2001

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

HISTORIC SEMINAR ON SECTION 7E OF THE INCOME TAX ORDINANCE, 2001: TAX PAYERS ALLIANCE PAKISTAN (TPAP) AND LAW & POLICY CHAMBERS CALL FOR ABOLISHMENT OF DEEMED RENTAL INCOME TAX IN PAKISTAN

Tax Payers Alliance Pakistan (TPAP), an initiative of economic think tank PRIME (Policy Research Institute of Market Economy), in collaboration with Law & Policy Chambers organized historic seminar on 9th March 2024 in Islamabad, shedding light on the contentious issue of the Deemed Rental Income Tax levied under section 7E of the Income Tax Ordinance, 2001 vide Finance Act, 2022.

The event brought together a diverse group of experts including economists, lawyers, tax professionals, civil society activists, and academia – attended by huge audience both in person and online - to discuss the detrimental impacts of this tax on the public.

Mr. Umer Ijaz Gilani, Advocate Supreme Court, elucidated the legal intricacies surrounding this tax, while discussing in detail its background and repercussions. He very nicely described the difference between “deemed income” and “non-existent/hypothetical income” to make it easily understandable to even a layman. Mr. Ali Salman, Executive Director PRIME, highlighted the sheer violation of fair taxation principles and the need to protect property rights. Mr. Mahmood Khalid, Senior Research Economist, Pakistan Institute of Development Economics (PIDE) provided insights from a tax policy perspective, and Barrister Junaid Ahmed, joining virtually from Karachi, contributed invaluable insights regarding the implications of this tax for inheritance cases.

The Deemed Rental Income Tax, introduced vide Finance Act 2022, has been under scrutiny for its constitutionality and alignment with public policy. Notably, both the Islamabad High Court (IHC) and Peshawar High Court (PHC) have already declared it unconstitutional, with the matter currently sub judice before the Supreme Court of Pakistan.

The overwhelming consensus among the participants was that the deemed rental income tax, as stipulated under Section 7E of the Income Tax Ordinance, 2001, is not only unconstitutional and ultra vires but also runs contrary to public policy. The arguments put forth during the seminar highlighted the adverse effects of this tax provision on fair taxation principles, property rights protection, and the overall welfare of taxpayers.

Given the compelling evidence presented at the seminar, Tax Payers Alliance Pakistan (TPAP) unequivocally calls for the immediate abolishment of the deemed rental income tax, void ab-initio. TPAP firmly believes that this tax not only violates the fundamental rights of taxpayers but also undermines the principles of fairness and hampers economic growth.

According to Mr. Anas Farhan, Convener Tax Payers Alliance Pakistan (TPAP), this seminar marks a significant step towards advocating for fair and just taxation policies in Pakistan. TPAP has also strongly urged the Government for abolishment of Section 7E, while submitting budgetary proposals to Revenue Division/Federal Board of Revenue (FBR) for the year 2024-25, he said.

Tax Payers Alliance Pakistan (TPAP) is a potent pressure group, comprising citizens of Pakistan from all walks of life to advise, educate and influence the Government and Public Policy in Pakistan to lowering the taxes on businesses and individuals, simplify the taxation regime, and to urge the government to eliminate undue and wasteful expenditures. PRIME Institute (Policy Research Institute of Market Economy) serves as its Secretariat in Islamabad.

TPAP Submitted Sales Tax Proposals 2024-25

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

TPAP Submitted Sales Tax Proposal 2024-25

Tax Payers Alliance Pakistan (TPAP), an initiative of economic think tank PRIME, submitted budgetary sales tax proposals to the Revenue Division/Federal Board of Revenue (FBR) in Pakistan for the upcoming Finance Bill 2024.

The proposal was developed by TPAP Team: Mr. Anas Farhan, Vice President ZTBL & PRIME Research Fellow from Islamabad, Mr. Usman Azmat, Advocate High Court from Lahore and Ms. Sehrish Naz, Economic Analyst FPCCI from Karachi, in consultation with the TPAP’s members comprising of a group of tax experts from across Pakistan, including representatives of Salaried Class Alliance (SCA) Mr. Shameer Muhammad Haroon, Member ICAP and Mr. Amer Sharif, Assistant Manager Treasury KAPCO. Subject proposal is aimed at simplifying tax regulations and reducing the compliance burden on taxpayers. This proposal aims to create a fairer and more efficient tax system in Pakistan that can provide sustainable funding for public expenditures.

According to experts, existing sales tax rate of eighteen percent is too much high and Government must consider to bring it down to single digit. Therefore, they have proposed a rate of nine percent for Budget 2024-25. Adjustment of input tax by some sectors of economy has also become complex and challenging, therefore it should also be simplified. Experts have proposed zero-rate sales tax on medicines. According to them, these life-saving items are out of reach of common man due to extraordinary sales tax thereon. Tax experts also highlighted to implement automated refund processing across the board instead of this facility to only few sectors, giving rise to discriminatory treatment. Existing sales tax withholding regime is also creating nuisance and distortion, therefore experts have proposed revamping it altogether.

Overall, TPAP’s proposal is a crucial contribution to the ongoing debate on sales tax reform in Pakistan. It provides a well-argued and clear case for a simpler, fairer, and more efficient tax system that could benefit both taxpayers and the wider economy initiative.

Tax Payers Alliance Pakistan Sales Tax Proposals for Budget 2024-25

Incredible things happen when taxpayers unite and raise their voice to advocate for positive change in the taxation system.

Revolutionizing Taxation: TPAP submitted Income Tax Proposals 2024-25 for Reduced and Uniform Tax Rates ensuing a Fairer and Simpler Tax System

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

Revolutionizing Taxation: TPAP Submitted Income Tax Proposal 2024-25 for Reduced and Uniform Tax Rates Ensuring a Fairer and Simpler Tax System

Tax Payers Alliance Pakistan (TPAP), an initiative of economic think tank PRIME, submitted budgetary proposal to the Revenue Division/Federal Board of Revenue (FBR) in Pakistan, aimed at reforming the income tax system to promote simplicity, transparency, and compliance. The proposal generated in response to the FBR’s solicitation of ideas for the upcoming Finance Bill 2024.

The proposal was developed by TPAP Team: Mr. Anas Farhan, Vice President ZTBL & PRIME Research Fellow from Islamabad, Mr. Usman Azmat, Advocate High Court from Lahore and Ms. Sehrish Naz, Economic Analyst FPCCI from Karachi, in consultation with the TPAP’s members comprising of a group of tax experts from across Pakistan, including representatives of Salaried Class Alliance (SCA) Mr. Shameer Muhammad Haroon, Member ICAP and Mr. Amer Sharif, Assistant Manager Treasury KAPCO. Subject proposal is aimed at simplifying tax regulations and reducing the compliance burden on taxpayers. The focus of the proposed tax reforms is to eliminate taxes that are unjustified, discriminatory, do not contribute to the national exchequer, and have become redundant. This proposal aims to create a fairer and more efficient tax system in Pakistan that can provide sustainable funding for public expenditures.

The proposed reforms are imperative for the promotion of compliance and broadening of the tax base. The prevalent ambiguities, complexities and distortions from discriminatory application of taxes are the underlying reasons for suboptimal performance of tax administration and low revenue collection. The government needs to move away from regressive and discriminatory tax regime towards flat, low rate and predictable taxes for transparency, compliance and broadening of tax base.

TPAP’s proposal emphasizes the significance of streamlining the tax system and lessening the compliance burden on taxpayers. They argued that a flat and low-rate taxation system would accomplish these objectives while also promoting economic growth and reducing inequality. The proposal would eliminate the current complex system of tax brackets and exemptions, reducing the need for expensive tax planning and compliance.

Overall, TPAP’s proposal is a crucial contribution to the ongoing debate on tax reform in Pakistan. It provides a well-argued and clear case for a simpler, fairer, and more efficient tax system that could benefit both taxpayers and the wider economy initiative.

Tax Payers Alliance Pakistan Income Tax Proposals for Budget 2024-25

Incredible transformations unfold when taxpayers unite and amplify their voice to advocate for positive change in the taxation system.

Same old govt, new economic path?

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

Same old govt, new economic path?

Proposing four key reforms to transform the nation’s economic landscape

Author: Zeeshan Hashim

Pakistan held a general election on February 8th, 2024, and the Pakistan Muslim League-Nawaz (PML-N) formed its government on March 4th, 2024. Mian Shehbaz Sharif, who led the previous government under the Pakistan Democratic Movement (PDM) coalition, is the current prime minister.

However, according to major macroeconomic indicators like inflation, growth rate, and unemployment, the performance of the PDM government hasn’t been impressive.

When PDM assumed office in April 2022, the economy was not functioning well. Rather than pursuing structural reforms that could bring long-term gains, the government decided to maintain the status quo and stabilise the economy using conventional tools that have a long history of failure. As a result, almost two years have passed, and the economic situation remains dire.

The new government may repeat past mistakes, but good hope remains for economic reforms. In this article, I propose four major reforms that can benefit the economy in the long run.

Firstly, rationalising the current economic model is a complex but necessary task. The model has failed and will only produce the same results if it remains in its present form. It has weak institutions, relies on debts and remittances, has an uncompetitive industrial structure, declining exports, brain drain, a lower tax base, economic uncertainty, regulatory burden, and a large government size.

To survive, the government is raising taxes at the cost of savings, consumption, and citizens’ welfare.

It is necessary to audit the entire economic structure, analysing what works and what does not, and removing all inefficiencies.

Without it, no policy is effective since these inefficiencies are deeply embedded in the present model. This long, continuous process needs improvement at each stage but must be done as soon as possible.

Secondly, creating state institutions that ensure the rule of law and accountability.

It also requires a strong political commitment despite high political costs to the dominant state institutions that maintain the status quo. They may prefer to keep their present position. But if they are concerned about the country’s development, they must not create barriers to institutional reforms.

Thirdly, we require market-led reforms that facilitate the growth of the private sector in the market. The private sector is the main driving force behind economic development, job creation, tax revenue, lower inflation, and an improved standard of living for the citizens. A stronger market paves the way for a stronger economy.

Unfortunately, doing business in Pakistan is not easy due to various factors. Some are institutional, such as corruption and regulatory burdens, while others are structural, such as a lower comparative advantage in the competitive market. To address these issues, we need institutional reforms to tackle the former and industrial policy to address the latter.

My fourth suggestion is about industrial policy. It doesn’t involve creating a further government footprint in the market while eliminating some. Its economic justification is simple: internalising externalities to capture learning and innovation and offsetting those externalities that cause market failure. Its objective is to promote industrial development to improve productive capacity and diversification in the economy and to facilitate some industries to gain a comparative advantage in the local and international markets. It will ultimately increase the market size and boost the export sector.

Regarding industrial policy, the most influential economist, Dani Rodrik, warns, “The kind of discipline that’s required is the discipline of monitoring, figuring out whether what you’re doing is working, and being able to move away from mistakes when things aren’t working. Successful industrial policy is not about picking winners; it’s about letting the losers go. Some of the worst cases of industrial policy are when you keep putting good money after bad.”

Therefore, before starting the industrial policy, Pakistan must ensure its policymakers and political economy are efficient enough to maintain that discipline Rodrik advises. Otherwise, a new industrial policy will create new evils.

Almost all industrialised countries, including East Asian economies, have achieved economic success due to the abovementioned factors. These are not easy to implement and require strong political commitment, which is why not all countries are successful economically.

However, the evidence confirms that these policies work and have contributed to the economic success of many countries.

THE WRITER IS A RESEARCH SCHOLAR AT THE PRIME INSTITUTE, A DOCTORAL RESEARCHER AT BRUNEL UNIVERSITY AND A LECTURER OF ECONOMICS AT THE UNIVERSITY OF BEDFORDSHIRE

The article was originally published in 'The Express Tribune' on March 18, 2024

Harnessing Population Dividends For Growth: The View From The Global South

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

Harnessing Population Dividends For Growth: The View From The Global South

Instead of fear mongering about large populations causing poverty, countries in the Global South must realize that underdevelopment is a consequence of policy failure. Large populations can provide dividends for growth if the right mix of governance exists

Author: Zafar U. Ahmed

There has long been an ongoing debate about whether a large population of a country or a large global population is a problem or an asset in attaining economic growth and development. More recently, the human population has been blamed as a key reason for the climate crisis by its proponents.

Globally, birth rates have been declining steadily for many decades; the total fertility rate now averages 2.4 children per woman, although high rates of fertility persist in many regions throughout the world. The replacement fertility rate is 2.1, which would maintain the current population number – provided a low child mortality rate.

By 2017, more than half of the world’s couples were producing fewer than 2.1 babies per mother. In the United States, it’s 1.8. In China and the United Kingdom, it’s 1.7. In Canada and Poland, it’s 1.5. In Hong Kong, Japan, and Spain, it’s 1.4. In Italy, Greece, and Portugal, it’s 1.3. In South Korea, it’s 1.1. The only reason population in the US, Canada and Australia is not falling is due to continuing immigration.

Prof B. Hartmann from Hampshire College explains that “the main reason the world population will likely grow by 2 to 3 billion more people before it stabilizes is that a large portion of the population in the Global South is young and approaching child-bearing age. Over time, this ‘demographic momentum’ will peter out as the present large generation of young people gets older and birth rates continue to decline worldwide.”

The fertility rate has to be seen in the context of the prevailing death rate. Where the death rate is high and the expected average length of life is low, the population growth rate will be lower despite a high fertility rate. If current trends continue unabated, sub-Saharan Africa will go from 1 billion people to 3 billion, but that assumes that the population continues to grow linearly by the present rate. This expectation however, may be unrealistic, and death rates have a tendency to decrease as development outcomes improve.

In 2020, Lancet, the medical science journal, published a massive study, giving population scenarios in 195 countries. According to their forecast, the global population will peak in 2064 at 9.79 billion, and gradually decline to 8.79 billion by 2100. By then, the fertility rate will have dropped to only 1.66 globally. The study estimates that the global population will likely peak below the carrying capacity.

Many countries are now investing in controlling falling birth rates to overcome a shortage of workers. For instance, Japan and Russia are struggling to give incentives for population growth.

The average consumption per person in Britain is 25 times what the average consumption per person is in many developing countries, according to Prof M. Connally at Columbia University. The per capita energy consumption in the US is 30 times what it is in many developing countries.

Statistics from the UN Food and Agricultural Organization show that from 1961 to 2002, the available food supply per person went up by 24.4%. Similarly, recent and past reports of the high-level panel of experts on Food Security and Nutrition, and also the UNDP, explain that there is enough food and water to go around (L. Mehta). The largest increase in food production was observed in developing countries, particularly in India and China (Sen, 1998), "

In his 1968 book The Population Bomb, P Ehrlich popularised Malthus’s ideas of impending doom by a growing population and a scarcity of resources – Ehrlich predicted that by the 1980s, famines would be commonplace and global death rates would rise. But like Malthus’ own predictions in the 1800s, this prediction also proved wrong - death rates continue to drop and globally average calorie consumption has increased."From 1980 to 2020, J Simon’s Abundance Index, which calculates the ratio of the price of basic commodities and hourly wages – how much people can buy, rose many times over, showing a much-enhanced purchasing power."

In most developed countries, greenhouse gas emissions per person peaked in the 1970s and where population growth has been low, as in Europe, total emissions have since declined. However, this direct decline in emissions in rich countries is deceptive. Higher impacts per affluent person accentuate the impact of any population increase and the benefits of a population decrease. Moreover, increasing trade means that rich countries consume goods made in other countries, with the emissions associated with making those products assigned to the producing country”, according to Prof. I. Lowe at the Griffith University in Australia.

The top ten economies (by PPP. not nominal GDP) of the world show that a large population is not at all necessarily an economic disadvantage. There is no credible or agreed scientific yardstick to determine an optimum population size. In his 1968 book The Population Bomb, P Ehrlich popularised Malthus’s ideas of impending doom by a growing population and a scarcity of resources – Ehrlich predicted that by the 1980s, famines would be commonplace and global death rates would rise. But like Malthus’ own predictions in the 1800s, this prediction also proved wrong - death rates continue to drop and globally average calorie consumption has increased.

In population literature, carrying capacity refers to the maximum number of organisms that an ecosystem can sustain indefinitely.

What is the carrying capacity of the earth for humans? There is disagreement among scientists on how to calculate that, and estimates vary dramatically. Generally, estimates lie anywhere between 4 billion humans and 16 billion on the higher end. But some pessimists think it’s just 2 billion, and some optimists think it could go as high as 100 billion. Therefore, there is such fundamental disagreement on the method that estimates have no credence.

As discussed above, in the West and most parts of the developed world, the population has been declining for the last few decades. During this century, exponential population growth is projected, primarily in Africa. The continent’s population growth is a result of demographic transition: mortality rates are decreasing faster than birth rates, partly due to new medical solutions that help fight infections.

There is nothing unusual or exclusive about Africa’s demographic transition. For example, in Europe, this transition occurred in the second half of the 19th century, when the population of Europe grew from 224 million in 1820 to 498 million in 1913. At the end of the process, both rates are lower, leading to a population that is stable or shrinking.

In parts of Africa, censuses are conducted rarely and selectively, so the actual population growth rate may be slightly lower than reported. Secondly, the growth rate cannot be endlessly extrapolated at the same rate, it varies dynamically due to many factors.

Since the population in the West has already been in a decline since the 1970s, population alarmists by implication mean that the population in Africa and parts of Asia and Latin America needs to be reduced significantly to stop what they see as overconsumption and degradation of natural resources and to alleviate the climate crisis. But the stark reality is that the West and developed countries consume 20 to 30 times more per person than is consumed by people in developing countries. And per capita CO2 emissions are far higher in the West, especially when manufacturing facilities based abroad are counted. So, a reduction in the population of the West and developed countries will be 20-30 times more effective per capita, for the purpose. Rationally then, a population reduction ought to be focussed on the West and in the high-income economies rather than on very low-consuming African, Asian or Latin American countries. Interestingly, the population alarmist Activists often receive funding and training for their activities from the West.

Alarmists about population growth commonly begin with an acknowledgement that it is the combination of such growth and increased consumption that is responsible for what they fear is catastrophic environmental decline. As Prof R. Fletcher at the Wageningen University in Netherlands) puts it, “yet in so doing, they frequently shift quite quickly from a brief nod to the latter to sustained focus on the former, contending that while of course it is overconsumption in a few wealthy countries that is the principal source of environmental degradation currently, imagine how much worse the problem would be if all of the world’s poor end up consuming at similar rates as well… And in the process, inequality itself is actually defended in the interest of sustainability”.

People make decisions in light of realities. In countries without social security for the elderly, children and sons are seen as a support in later years. In poor countries, giving birth to more children is a way to potentially increase incomes. In poor rural areas, more offspring meant more people to do the work. In many cultures, girls go to the other family after marriage. So do their grandchildren.

A study by M. Rubio on fertility decline in developed countries, such as Japan, found that it was more of a function of the rising cost of childcare and children’s educational needs and that of women’s emancipation which resulted in delayed marriages and a rise in the number of people preferring to remain single. In affluent countries, children are a significant financial burden, so people often defer childbearing to establish their career and home, then limit births to ensure they can provide well for their children.

“The demographic transition to low fertility occurred in country after country as parents gained confidence that their first few children would live. Then there was no advantage and plenty of disadvantage to having large families,” according to Sterling & Platt at the University of Pennsylvania. In general, many people can agree that family planning is an appropriate response to unwanted fertility, and that a broader development approach is called for to deal with high desired fertility.

"Large populations offer the advantage of internal economies of scale and are also a highly lucrative and attractive market for external businesses."

Studies by economics Nobel laureate Simon Kuznets have shown that there is no clear link between population growth and economic growth or poverty. “Kuznets explained that the direct relationship between population and growth or poverty is difficult to establish… any ‘direct causal relation’ between them ‘may be quite limited’… [Others], likewise, reasoned that rapid population growth is the consequence and not the cause of economic and social inequalities. Hence, there is a need to address economic development first and the decline in fertility rates will naturally follow… the problem of shortage is caused principally by the inequitable distribution of wealth and resources among the world’s population rather than the increase in numbers… Antonio, et al.(2004) further argued that the Philippine experience proves that higher population densities do not translate to lower personal incomes… Hong Kong, Singapore and Korea have higher population densities than the Philippines, yet they have higher personal incomes as well,” (Rubio, for SEPO, Philippines).

A population number does not tell us whether it is too much or not. It depends upon so many other things. Large populations offer the advantage of internal economies of scale and are also a highly lucrative and attractive market for external businesses.

Lyla Mehta at the IDS at Sussex University emphasizes that “this fixation with overpopulation diverts attention from more crucial issues… we need to link population debates with issues concerning unequal and skewed patterns of consumption, allocation, and distribution… rather than drawing on simplistic universalizing notions of scarcity…There is currently an explosion of food banks in the UK, and about 8% of the population is food insecure. The UK is the fifth richest country in the world by nominal GDP. Malnutrition and hunger in the UK are not because of overpopulation but instead due to government policies of austerity, cuts, and due to rising poverty, and inequality… the scare of scarcity and overpopulation remains a means of diverting attention away from the causes of poverty and inequality that may implicate the politically powerful.”

Population alarmists’ talking points sometimes make vacuous arguments, for instance, that if the world were to have just 1 billion, people there would be so many available jobs for everyone! That fails to understand that with so many fewer people, the world’s economy would also shrink – there would be a massive drop in available jobs. Another argument not thought through is that with fewer people, the total consumption would proportionally go down. That is quite unlikely, since if there are fewer people and the same resources available, the consumption per person would almost certainly go up, and that is often the aim when planning a small family.

"The developing countries of Asia, Africa and Latin America ought to be clear that a growing population is not a burden, but must be fostered into their greatest asset."

Discussing the relationship of population growth, capacity for food production, and the abundance of African land, Allen Kelly’s paper cites Nikos Alexandratos' (1986) study of 38 countries which concludes that "...a country’s capacity to feed its growing population... depends only weakly on its land endowments per se..." Gale Johnson (1984) is unequivocal on this point: “... there is not the slightest shred of evidence that continued poor performance of food and agriculture in most of Africa is in any way related to resource restraint."

Fletcher summarizes “until this obscene inequity, and the economic system driving it, are adequately addressed, all the attention to population growth in the world will do nothing to halt our environmental and poverty [concerns]… in discussions of sustainability, population growth should be the last issue addressed, while instead, it is increasingly becoming the first, if not primary, problem to be identified.”

The developing countries of Asia, Africa and Latin America ought to be clear that a growing population is not a burden, but must be fostered into their greatest asset. The rationale for countries is the welfare of their people. The people are nurtured through proper healthcare, education, social protection and by facilitating their economic enterprise. When individuals in a country get the opportunity and are supported in reaching their potential then those countries flourish. States have to live up to their responsibilities for good governance and equal opportunity for all, as they are entrusted to do by citizens. A large population does not cause poverty, but bad governance and bad policies do.

The article was originally published in Friday Times on February 28, 2024

100-day agenda for new govt

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

100-day agenda for new govt

It will provide trigger for economic growth without any major investments


Ali Salman | February 26, 2024

It is natural that citizens and voters build up expectations from a new government to deliver them relief. A newly elected government, which will hopefully take the reins soon in Islamabad, will also be under pressure to make such announcements, which can earn them acceptability.

A new government is often expected to announce a 100-day agenda, and in this article, I propose one. The announcements should, in my opinion, be on the one hand meaningful enough to create an impact and should be bold enough to signal a change on the other hand.

There is the usual caveat of pragmatism, especially given the IMF programme, but I also see there is always room for the new government to take such decisions, which are difficult politically. Let me present the 100-day agenda for the new government.

Abolish non-electricity dues

According to the information available at the Ministry of Energy website, electricity consumers pay eight different types of taxes and charges, which include electricity duty, general sales tax, PTV licence fee, finance cost surcharge, extra tax, further tax, income tax and sales tax.

The withholding tax collected is not adjusted because of the lack of an automated mechanism and is appropriated in the case of non-filers of income tax returns. Deduction of sales tax from commercial bills of non-filers gives legitimacy to the non-filers.

Electricity users should be obliged to pay only electricity dues. They do not need any subsidies, however, they must not be penalised for failure of the country’s tax administration.

That is why it is important to remove electricity distribution companies from the clutches of the federal government, while strengthening the institutional regulatory framework. The job of electricity companies is to sell electricity to consumers efficiently and not to collect taxes on behalf of the Federal Board of Revenue (FBR).

Announce tax holiday for small businesses

Despite claims of automation and simplification, the tax policy and tax administration in Pakistan pose a major stumbling block for the registration of new businesses.

There is a steady flow of new companies being formed under the SECP, however, a majority of entrepreneurs start informally or as a sole proprietor. We need to encourage them to join the formal economy and help them to become profitable.

The new government should announce income tax holiday for three years for all micro and small businesses registered within 100 days of the new government provided they open a bank account and register with the FBR to file returns.

Open trade with India

Food items constitute the bulk of Consumer Price Index (CPI) basket, particularly for the low-income households, reaching 60% of their average household expenditure.

The new government should resume trade in fruits and vegetables with India, allowing consumers and farmers on both sides to enjoy benefits of continuous supply of eatables at affordable prices.

Allow formal oil trade with Iran

According to official estimates released in 2023, almost 18% of the oil consumed in Pakistan is smuggled from Iran, which is then distributed across the country.

As Pakistan has announced the completion of its side of the Iran-Pakistan gas pipeline recently, its calculations show that it is ready to take the risk to avoid $18 billion of penalties, which is three times more than the IMF programme.

In this environment, it will be beneficial for Pakistan’s economy and its government to open formal oil trade links with Iran. This will also bring back Rs60 billion to the exchequer, which is the lost tax revenue.

Announce scholarships for young people

We are wasting billions of rupees each year in the higher education system. We need to divert a major chunk of this budget to technical and vocational education of our qualified young population.

The rate of unemployment is significantly higher among university graduates (about 30%, according to PIDE) as compared with those without university education.

On the other hand, Pakistan’s technical and vocational system continues to fall short of producing the required number of trained workforce to meet the national requirement. A major re-allocation to upgrade this system and the announcement of scholarships for at least 100,000 young people who qualify will be a great boost to the job market.

By announcing this 100-day agenda, the elected government can quickly create a positive environment for the country’s aspiring youth and help provide a trigger for economic growth without any major investments.

The potential for sustainable economic growth lies within our reach if we are ready to take such bold decisions for the welfare of people.

The writer is the founder and executive director of PRIME, an independent economic policy think tank

The article was originally published in The Express Tribune on February 26, 2024

New Privatisation Framework For Pakistan | Event Report

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

New Privatisation Framework for Pakistan

Report on Findings from Consultative Workshop with Stakeholders

Download the PDF right now by clicking the link below or scroll down to read.

Picture library

1. Introduction

The Policy Research Institute of Market Economy (PRIME), as part of the project titled “Privatisation Acceleration Initiative” conducted the “Workshop of Privatisation and PSE Policies of the Federal Government” on the Thursday 6th of December 2023, at the Best Western Premier in Islamabad.

The workshop had participants/ representation from the Competition Commission of Pakistan, the Petroleum Division (Energy Ministry), the PSEs Zarai Taraqiati Bank Limited (formerly Agricultural Development Bank of Pakistan), regulator National Electric Power Regulatory Authority, think tank Center for Economic Research in Pakistan, and the multilateral lender Asian Development Bank (ADB).

The session was chaired by the Privatisation Minister Fawad Hasan Fawad, and was conducted by the Executive Director PRIME Ali Salman and Programme Director Syed Ali Ehsan. Political Economist and PRIME Distinguished Fellow Dr. Khalil Ahmad facilitated the discussions.

The first segment of the workshop contained a presentation by Lahore University of Management Sciences (LUMS) Fellow at PRIME Hassan Abbas, with his focus on facts related to privatisation.

Next was an interactive session with participants exchanging their diagnoses on repeated failures to privatise Public Sector Enterprise (PSE). This was followed by a discussion session on amendments to the privatisation policy and the PSE Policy. The discussion was held under Chatham House Rules.

The Workshop was concluded with comments by the Privatisation Minister followed by a networking exchange over Hi-Tea.

2 Identification of Problems

The first interactive discussion revolved around the identification of recurring systemic patterns hindering past privatisation attempts by various governments.

2.1 Problems Stemming from Human Resource Complexities

A significant number of pressures emanate from the labor force related complexities. These were traced to opposition by unions, over extended job contracts which no new owner would plausibly try to accept.

2.1.1 Political Resistance by employee unions

The participants raised the matter of employee unions blocking privatisation attempts through political resistance and legal measures. Employee unions in many commercial PSEs have direct affiliation with political parties. As large, organized voter segment, employee unions are able to exert significant pressure on political representatives to oppose privatisation.

2.1.2 Legal Resistance by Unions and Special Interests

Another mechanism that has blocked privatisation efforts has been the invocation of courts by special interests. Unions as well as ex-servicemen communities, and even Public Interest Litigation lawyers are able to obtain legal stay orders at different levels of a privatisation process to completely paralyze the process.

2.1.3 Unsuitable Human Resource and Rigid Ecosystem

Private investors seeking to turnaround PSEs are unable to relocate, dismiss or terminate the employment contracts of unsuitable HR due to internal organizational rules, or legal protections contained within past legal precedent established by the judicial courts.

Many PSEs contain specialized positions which would otherwise not exist in the private sector. Mostly, these employees cannot be utilized under a new management plan brought in by the private investor. At the same time, the courts have generally protected the positions and financial compensation of such employees, adding a layer of management complexity, and an additional cost burden without value addition.

2.1.4 Conflicting Interests of Management

It was identified during the session that Commercial PSEs provided civil servants with the opportunity to draw compensation up to three or four times higher than their salaries. Many serving civil servants are on the boards of Commercial PSEs.

On the other hand, bureaucracy will frequently collude with politicians and aid them in developing their political capital by facilitating the creation of low-level jobs in PSEs and hiring those with political references to fill the positions.

A major chunk of public sector procurement occurs in PSEs, and this procurement is not transparent. Leakages in procurement may go towards benefiting unscrupulous and powerful employees such as those with influence in unions and management as well as political leaders and patrons, creating direct conflict with the privatisation process.

2.1.5 Legislative and Judicial Uncertainties

Amongst the identified issues were uncertainties caused by conflicting legislation. New laws conflict with older laws, creating ambiguity in what should be well-established processes. This coupled with a broad culture of judicial activism creates a negative environment for privatisation of PSEs. Significantly, G2G transactions are not dealt with clearly under the law.

3 Recommendations

After the identification of Problems, the participants engaged in a discussion around remedies to eliminating failure in privatisation attempts. These were shared as follows:
1. No court other than a specialized Privatisation Appellate Tribunal should be allowed to examine civil or criminal cases related to any privatisation transaction. In the past, even government entities have gone into litigations against the federal government.

2. Major modifications must be made in the Privatisation Commission ordinance as well as the regulations to modernize the privatisation framework, and to incorporate international best practices.

3. Contradictory and conflicting legislation/statutes which create procedural uncertainties must be reviewed and synchronized to eliminate procedural ambiguities in the privatisation process.

4. Political parties should clarify their position on the privatisation of PSEs, and specify their plans to a certain degree, so that political uncertainty around the issue can be mitigated.

5. A System of reward and punishment be adopted for the bureaucracy overseeing the privatisation process, and regular performance appraisal of the management overseeing the privatisation must be arranged periodically to ensure process continuity, and management effectiveness. Line Ministries managing PSEs must have answerable/accountable bureaucracies.

6. Parliamentary Committees in the National Assembly and Senate overseeing privatisation matters and PSE performance issues must play a more active role and provide more effective oversight and ownership to keep stakeholders accountable to privatisation goals.

7. Bundling of PSE verticals may be done after discussions with investor groups. If investors feel that they would draw greater benefit from purchasing a bundle of verticals together, and if Privatisation Commission deems greater value in terms of incoming receipts, then the organizational management can organize assets accordingly.

8. Use Special Purpose Entities (SPEs) as an off-balance sheet tool to park the liabilities of Commercial PSEs, whose compromised balance sheet may be the single biggest hinderance in their privatisation. An SPE holding company can be created to manage all these liabilities arising privatisation in one place. An SPE may not come into existence legally until a deal has been reached and finalized.

9. Exemption of Commercial PSEs from the conventional rules of the Public Procurement Regulatory Authority in order to improve their responsiveness to market forces responsiveness and operational environmental threats. Instead PPRA may work on a separate framework for procurement compliance for Commercial PSEs.

10. The Central Monitoring Unit of the Finance Division should be given time-bound objectives in regard to the management of PSEs, and those Commercial PSEs which are on the active privatisation list.

11. A periodical report on the financial performance of state-owned enterprises comparing them with their private sector counterparts should be prepared and published.

12. All PSEs should maintain an accurate Asset & Liability Register (Balance Sheet) and such statements need to be verified by credible and approved external auditors.

13. Financial review of PSEs should report any losses which the government might have parked or re- assigned for accounting purpose under any other name or entity.

14. An international case study or case studies may be prepared to showcase the benefits of successful privatisation to educate and build opinion with the academia. A public service campaign to build public opinion should also be utilized.

15. Training should be conducted by the Privatisation Commission for the benefit of any new organizational management team undertaking privatisation. This training should be compulsory for any management team as soon as their PSE has been added to the active privatisation list.

16. A conflict-of-interest policy needs to be introduced and implemented in the board meetings to ensure that those who are present at the board meeting do not have a commercial interest in the transactions. Disclosure rules may be reexamined and incorporated into organizational rules to minimize the possibility of board members’ interests conflicting with transparency and efficacy of the privatisation process.
PRIME values your feedback on the proposed privatisation framework. Click below to share your insights now. Your input is crucial to us!

Privatization of SOEs – A Story More of Failures

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

Privatization of SOEs – A Story More of Failures

<p class="story-excerpt" style="font-family: georgia, sans-serif; line-height: 21px; opacity: 1; padding: 0px; margin-top: 10px; margin-bottom: 0px; color: rgb(70, 68, 68); width: 832.469px; letter-spacing: normal; white-space-collapse: collapse;"
By Dr Khalil Ahmad  | Februrary 01, 2024

The issue of privatization of the SOEs is reflective of the complexity, ambivalence and indecisiveness of the public policy in Pakistan. These three traits are embedded in the politics and political struggle and form the core of political opportunism. 

 So, the fundamental question is how to decide: What to privatize and what not to privatize? What's the criteria? Also, why to privatize and why not to privatize? 

 Or, other than the security concerns, what criteria can be agreed upon regarding the question: what to privatize and what not to privatize?

 In this regard, a historical review of the attempts at privatization of the SOEs reveals the two significant aspects the issue of privatization needs to be tackled with. 

 First is the theoretical and political side, and the other is the practical side of the issue of the privatization. Logically speaking, the second one depends on the theoretical and political side of the issue. That is, here in this case the issue of privatization depends on one's theory of state, that is, what political philosophy is working behind the various approaches to the issue of privatization. 

 But as is evident, mostly there is no theoretical and political clarity as the case of Pakistan Peoples Party shows; it favors both nationalization and privatization at the same time. Or it’s political populism that determines their politics. 

 That means there is too much confusion on the political front. As far as privatization of the SOEs is concerned, almost all the political parties position themselves as it suits them. Now they favor it and now they don’t. 

 It is only the Leftist groups that have political clarity and a clearly defined position regarding the privatization of the SOEs. 

 And there is another factor and that is, vested interests of various actors, such as labor unions, including the political actors. 

 So, to say, from the beginning, the state of Pakistan took itself as an all-powerful state, leaving no space for the private initiatives to try their hands. And somehow that was the expectation created by the political-electoral struggle also. That is how the statist political ideology formed and grew.

 Though, Pakistan has never been a totalitarian socialist state, but the political adventurism made use of the recipe of a mixed-economy (the third way) dominated by the public sector (1971-76) in Pakistan. That wiped out the gains made out of an experimental approach by the state which believed in extending a helping hand to the nascent private sector (1958-67). 

 That dealt, and proved to be a devastating blow to the sentiment of the private investors both local and foreign for a long time to come. (The foreign investors that came to Pakistan sought such protections that in the longer term burdened the people unbearably.) And it is that environment that strengthened the Pakistani version of the ideology of statism: it is the state that has to do everything. 

 That thinking resulted in an economic legacy consisting of a heavier footprint of the state (more than 200 SOEs, and 70% state footprint), that includes from commercial SOEs to non-commercial SOEs and what not. 

 Then, economically speaking, the pendulum oscillated to the other side. A period of correction ensued: De-nationalization, privatization and liberalization provided an impetus to the economic and financial activities still benefiting the society at large (1978-1986). 

 Another fact that must not be ignored is that some commercial monopolies, such as Karachi Electric (KE), Pakistan Telecommunication Corporation Limited (PTCL), were privatized in a way that was like a monopoly changing the hands only, and that brought no benefits to the consumers. That strengthened the statist ideology since the privatization proved not beneficial. 

 Not surprising that the statist ideology still prevails. The voices of nationalization of this or that privatized SOE, for instance, KE, are still heard. And it is this ambivalence of political philosophy on the part of political parties and political circles that don’t allow the private sector to take root, and thus competition. No doubt, that environment influenced and nurtured a specific section of the private sector also that is dependent on the doles from the state.

 In the final analysis, that ambivalence, instilled by the various political parties attempting privatization while in government and opposing it while not in government, that is, their opportunistic behaviour, and an anti-privatization environment, kept and keeps the state and its institutions confused as to the role of the state and indecisive as to the determination of the economic character of the state: To do business or not to do business. 

 Also, there is no clarity that how the privatization of the SOEs, by opening competition, brings not only political and economic stability, but prosperity also, and would allow the state to focus on its protective function. 

 Now even after 45 years, we are still considering of running the SOEs under this or that regulatory framework. We still lack and need theoretical-political clarity on the one hand, and on the other, equipping the government/political parties with regulatory tools that would help them accelerate and strengthen the process of privatization of the SOEs. 

 There is too less here to celebrate and too much to reflect on. No doubt, that’s the story more of failures.

Caretaker government’s economic reforms fall short of expectations

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

Caretaker government’s economic reforms fall short of expectations

The tax reforms proposed by the caretaker government illustrate a lack of understanding of the real issue as restructuring the tax administration does not address of high tax rate and narrow tax base. The absence of an equitable tax policy makes the problem more complicated.

Another area of concern is the privatization drive initiated by the caretaker government. While highlighting the fiscal burden and revenue constraints, ambitious hopes were built up for the privatization of loss-making State-Owned Enterprises (SOEs). However, bureaucratic hurdles and cumbersome processes prevented any tangible progress.

PRIME has published its quarterly assessment report, PRIME Plus January 2024, which analyzes the performance of the caretaker government in the areas of tax reforms and privatization, the macroeconomic performance of the country in Q2- FY2024, and potential challenges.

The report scrutinizes the tax administration restructuring plan proposed by the caretaker government as a way forward to address the fiscal challenges of the government. The most prominent component of the reform was the planned separation of the Inland Revenue Service and Customs Service for specialized roles and monitoring of their performance through oversight boards. Another feature is the separation of tax policy from operations.

The proposed reforms were insufficient to address the underlying causes of low tax revenues and a narrow tax base. The broadening of the tax base necessitates revision of the tax policy, if any at the moment, and lowering of the tax rates to encourage compliance of the citizens. After the 18th Constitutional Amendment, some taxes are provincial subjects and some are federal. People face hurdles in dealing with multiple tax authorities. The proposed reform fails to address this problem. Moreover, no attention was paid to improve the coordination between the federal and provincial tax administrations.

the report also highlights the progress made by the caretaker government on privatization. The government was able to privatize the Heavy Electrical Complex but could not achieve any significant progress to privatize any of the top ten loss-making entities. Seven of the top ten loss making entities are power sector distribution companies. The government remained indecisive about the way forward; provincialization of companies, complete or partial privatization, or supervision by performance monitoring units.

The privatization of Pakistan International Airlines also faced setbacks as the government missed all deadlines due to the inability to get requisite audited reports and No Objection Certificates (NOC) from the creditors. The plan was to segregate core and noncore assets, transfer liabilities to a holding company, and present core assets free from liabilities for privatization. However, the government could not get the requisite NOCs.

On the fiscal front, there is no significant change and business as usual policy is observed. The government relied heavily on borrowing from banks to finance expenditures. The FBR revenues increased by 30 percent in H1 FY 2024 compared to last year while expenditures increased by 57 percent. The fiscal deficit stood at 2.3 percent compared to 2 percent last year and the government borrowed Rs. 2.6 trillion compared to Rs. 1.78 trillion in the corresponding period last year. The government made difficult decisions such as raising power and gas tariffs; however, the circular debt continues to mount as underlying causes remain unaddressed.

Inflation continues to remain a challenge and people have experienced an exponential fall in their purchasing power. In Q2 FY 2024, the average CPI inflation stood at 28.7 percent as compared to 24.9 percent in FY 2023. The government’s decision to pass on the cost of utilities to the consumers without addressing policy and institutional inefficiencies may prove to be futile and keep inflation unanchored.

The reforms and initiatives proclaimed by the caretaker government fall short to achieve desired outcomes. Reforms envisaged in haste without due deliberation will not be effective. Tax reforms should comprise formulation of a tax policy and reducing the number and rates of taxes along with the restructuring. The incoming government needs to continue the efforts to privatize SOEs to reduce the burden on the government. It is also recommended that government expenditures are carefully reviewed.

For inquiries, please contact farhan@primeinstitute.org or call +92 (51) 8 31 43 38

Unravelling the conundrum of failed welfare policies

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

Unravelling the conundrum of failed welfare policies

Despite subsidies and social programmes, inflation has driven 5% rise in poverty


BILAL ZAHID | January 29, 2024

The most recent World Bank report, released in October 2023, sheds light on Pakistan’s concerning poverty landscape. It’s estimated that in 2023, the poverty headcount has surged to 39.4%, a worrying increase of 5% from the year before.

What is particularly noteworthy is that the poverty level now is higher than it was five years ago. This is a worrisome departure from Pakistan’s earlier success in steadily reducing poverty over the preceding decade.

Despite Pakistan’s recent focus on welfare, including increased spending on social programmes and widespread subsidies, the results have been concerning.

Efforts such as the Benazir Income Support Programme (BISP) aim to safeguard the underprivileged, while subsidies aim to shield the masses and the economy from the shock of rising food and energy prices.

However, citizens are facing more difficulties, with rising poverty rates and stagnant per capita income over the past five years. This outcome contradicts the anticipated improvements.

The preceding government purposefully ramped up spending on subsidies and social protection programmes in pursuit of a stronger social welfare system. Over the past five years, allocations for subsidies, BISP, and social protection surged, averaging 14.2% of the federal government’s expenditure – an uptick from the previous five-year average of 7%, which saw spending on a declining trend.

The trajectory depicts a clear increase: it began at 5.9% in 2019, doubled for the following two years, and peaked at an unprecedented 23% in 2022.

The effectiveness of these policies remains in question. While correlation isn’t causation, one must question why poverty reduction has reversed despite a greater focus on social welfare and subsidies?

The primary driver behind the resurgence of poverty has been the unexpected surge in inflation. The surge has had far-reaching implications on the overall cost of living, impacting the populace at large.


However, the middle class and impoverished citizens are the most affected, as their real incomes diminish and fail to keep pace with the inflationary pressures. The runaway inflation has rendered basic necessities prohibitively expensive, resulting in an estimated 20 million people slipping into poverty – a stark contrast to declining poverty rates in previous years.

The government attributes high inflation to the international commodity super cycle; however, this claim is untrue. Other countries in the region haven’t witnessed such a spike in inflation. This is because inflation is inherently a local phenomenon shaped by local policy decisions.

At its core, fiscal indiscipline stands as the root cause. The surge in subsidies amid growing fiscal imprudence and record deficits is not without repercussions. The government finds itself in a net borrowing position, with soaring debt levels nearing the point of unsustainability.

Financing the escalating fiscal deficits through bank borrowings has fuelled the expansion of the monetary base, contributing significantly to the inflation rate, which peaked at an alarming 38%.

Contrary to their intended purpose, substantial subsidies have negatively impacted the economic landscape by distorting the price system. The resulting adjustments are considerably more painful and less subtle.

While broad subsidies lack merit, there is a case for a targeted programme like BISP. However, it demands a more deliberate and focused strategy with clear milestones to uplift families from poverty within specified timeframes and the establishment of performance metrics to gauge progress.

There’s a necessity to transition away from providing indefinite monthly stipends and to measure progress not solely based on the number of beneficiaries and total cash disbursed.

While there is much rhetoric advocating for the continuation of subsidies and the expansion of social protection, these measures rarely assist people in breaking out of the poverty cycle. This is evident in recent years despite a focus on welfare policies.

It’s apparent that the current approach falls short, especially considering Pakistan’s consistent reduction in poverty rates over the previous decade with relatively modest subsidies and safety nets. The unintended consequences – high inflation and a reversal in poverty reduction – underscore the necessity for a more balanced and sustainable strategy.

The best way forward is for the government to stop fuelling inflation. It needs to prioritise fiscal prudence across its expenditure spectrum, which involves enhancing the efficiency of public spending, reducing the government’s footprint, phasing out subsidies, and establishing clear milestones to limit welfare spending.

In essence, creating a supportive business environment and expanding employment opportunities through growth stand as the viable means to alleviate poverty. Prioritising fiscal responsibility and nurturing economic growth are crucial steps towards reorienting Pakistan’s course for effective poverty alleviation.

THE WRITER IS A FELLOW OF PRIME, AN INDEPENDENT ECONOMIC POLICY THINK TANK BASED IN ISLAMABAD

TThe article was originally published in The Express Tribune on January 29, 2023.

Privatization is the first step…

by PRIME Institute PRIME Institute No Comments

Privatization is the first step...

By Dr Khalil Ahmad

In Czechoslovakia, they resolved that if privatisation needed to be done, it had to be done. They considered it as the first step towards transforming the economic system.

According to Dr Vaclav Klaus, once a finance minister, prime minister, and president of the Czech Republic, privatisation at a vast scale was done and it proved to be the first decisive step. It was like crossing the Rubicon. No doubt, the political costs were unavoidable but it had to be done and needed to be done as quickly as possible.

There were other aspects that assumed a number of things to be part and parcel of privatisation. The people in Czechoslovakia and other countries also (like Pakistan) believed that in a market economy as compared to the command economy or centrally planned economy every firm and economic activity had to succeed and they attached an undisputed efficiency with every private firm.

Whereas as is evident that is not true even in a major, stable, developed economy. And of course, Dr Klaus says it is much less true in an economy in transition with a dramatically changing economic environment, in competition with much stronger partners from the rest of the world, and without sufficient experience.

As is said, “There are no free lunches,” Dr Vaclav Klaus reminds, likewise, there are no ‘free’ economic transitions. The ‘economic transition’ is a very costly process. It’s an investment and usually, like any investment, has costs and benefits and the business people know that usually when you make an investment, you pay the costs first and you may get the benefits with a considerable delay.

Hence, according to Dr Klaus, the transition from communism to a free society was an investment in certain respects, and the costs were really enormous.

So not only while transitioning from a command economy to a market economy has its costs, in converting a mixed economy into a free enterprise economy has its price also.

Dr Klaus makes a mention of the size of the costs his country had to go through. According to his estimates, in his country they were lower than in other countries. In the first three years of transition, they lost one third of their industrial output – one third.

As happens usually, if we take all of the business people, two would succeed and one would collapse. They lost one quarter of their agriculture output – one quarter – and they lost one fifth of their GDP - and it was lower than in most of the countries in transition.

No doubt, in Czechoslovakia too, transition and privatisation were connected with many business failures and the one who was blamed was the government, of course, not the individuals owning and managing those firms. Dr Klaus tells, it became fashionable to argue that the failures were caused by unsuccessful privatisation and an insufficient legislative and institutional framework.

Dr Klaus admits, both privatisation and the formation of new legislation of market accompanying institutions was as imperfect as any human activity. But the main problem, in his opinion, was that the citizens were not prepared to accept or to live with the phenomenon of a business failure, both at micro and macro level.

As far as foreign help in the process of transition is concerned, Dr Klaus tells that sometime back he was asked to give a speech together with German economists to compare the transition and transformation of Germany in the 1950s and the Czech Republic in the 1990s.

He flashes back, it was a very interesting exercise. One of the differences was really the fact that there was huge foreign help to Germany. We didn’t get it, we have really got nothing in the last ten years, and we didn’t ask for it. The role of the rest of the world in this respect was really zero.

Regarding foreign help, Dr Klaus is very blunt: I think that the typical foreign help was sending would-be advisors and consultants. It became one of the most profitable businesses in the 1990s – to become a consultant and advisor in the transforming societies.

The recommendations of these advisors and consultants weren’t useful and not very good. We know about the troubles that were experienced in South East Asia in the second half of the 1990s. Dr Klaus says, it has become an accepted truth that the policies of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) were a tragic mistake for all what happened in countries like Indonesia, Malaysia and elsewhere.

And, he goes on: I remember I made a well-known statement that was repeated many times, and Milton Friedman called it ‘Klaus Law.’ I was forced some eight or nine years ago in the World Bank in Washington to accept, when I was still the Minister for Finance, a foreign assistance loan, a technical assistance loan. I said we are not interested in a loan for inviting consultants and advisors.

If you are ready to give us a loan to build something, some infrastructure project we can discuss it, but a technical assistance loan? I am not interested.

Lesson for Pakistan: Wiping out the presence of the government from the domain of business, that is, privatization, has its costs and the costs will have to bear, because there is no perfectly infallible method is available to privatize a state-owned-enterprise. That amounts to saying that in altering an economic system, mind the privatization as the first step and be ready to bear the costs of that Change.

[Note: This article is based on a lengthy interview of Dr Vaclav Klaus.]